Strengths Of Transaction Cost Theory Of The Firm Essay

FOR philosophers the great existential question is: “Why is there something rather than nothing?” For management theorists the more mundane equivalent is: “Why do firms exist? Why isn't everything done by the market?”

Today most people live in a market economy, and central planning is remembered as the greatest economic disaster of the 20th century. Yet most people also spend their working lives in centrally planned bureaucracies called firms. They stick with the same employer for years, rather than regularly returning to the jobs market. They labour to fulfil the “strategic plans” of their corporate commissars. John Jacob Astor's American Fur Company made him the richest man in America in the 1840s. But it never consisted of more than a handful of people. Today Astor's company would not register as a blip on the corporate horizon. Firms routinely employ thousands of workers and move billions of dollars-worth of goods and services within their borders.

Why have these “islands of conscious power” survived in the surrounding “ocean of unconscious co-operation”, to borrow a phrase from D.H. Robertson, an economist? Classical economics had little to say about this question. Adam Smith opened “The Wealth of Nations” with a wonderful description of the division of labour in a pin factory, but he said nothing about the bosses who hired the pin-makers or the managers who organised them. Smith's successors said even less, either ignoring the pin factory entirely or treating it as a tedious black box. They preferred to focus on the sea rather than the islands.

Reprints

Who knows the secret of the black box?

The man who restored the pin factory to its rightful place at the heart of economic theory celebrates his 100th birthday on December 29th. The economics profession was slow to recognise Ronald Coase's genius. He first expounded his thinking about the firm in a lecture in Dundee in 1932, when he was just 21 years old. Nobody much listened. He published “The Nature of the Firm” five years later. It went largely unread.

But Mr Coase laboured on regardless: a second seminal article on “The Problem of Social Cost” laid the intellectual foundations of the deregulation revolution of the 1980s. Eventually, Mr Coase acquired an army of followers, such as Oliver Williamson, who fleshed out his ideas. In 1991, aged 80, he was awarded a Nobel prize. Far from resting on his laurels, Mr Coase will publish a new book in 2011, with Ning Wang of Arizona State University, on “How China Became Capitalist”.

His central insight was that firms exist because going to the market all the time can impose heavy transaction costs. You need to hire workers, negotiate prices and enforce contracts, to name but three time-consuming activities. A firm is essentially a device for creating long-term contracts when short-term contracts are too bothersome. But if markets are so inefficient, why don't firms go on getting bigger for ever? Mr Coase also pointed out that these little planned societies impose transaction costs of their own, which tend to rise as they grow bigger. The proper balance between hierarchies and markets is constantly recalibrated by the forces of competition: entrepreneurs may choose to lower transaction costs by forming firms but giant firms eventually become sluggish and uncompetitive.

How much light does “The Nature of the Firm” throw on today's corporate landscape? The young Mr Coase first grew interested in the workings of firms when he travelled around America's industrial heartland on a scholarship in 1931-32. He abandoned his textbooks and asked businessmen why they did what they did. He has long chided his fellow economists for scrawling hieroglyphics on blackboards rather than looking at what it actually takes to run a business. So it seems reasonable to test his ideas by the same empirical standards.

Mr Coase's theory continues to explain some of the most puzzling problems in modern business. Take the rise of vast and highly diversified business groups in the emerging world, such as India's Tata group and Turkey's Koc Holding. Many Western observers dismiss these as relics of a primitive form of capitalism. But they make perfect sense when you consider the transaction costs of going to the market. Where trust in established institutions is scarce, it makes sense for companies to stretch their brands over many industries. And where capital and labour markets are inefficient, it makes equal sense for companies to allocate their own capital and train their own loyalists.

But Mr Coase's narrow focus on transaction costs nevertheless provides only a partial explanation of the power of firms. The rise of the neo-Coasian school of economists has led to a fierce backlash among management theorists who champion the “resource-based theory” of the firm. They argue that activities are conducted within firms not only because markets fail, but also because firms succeed: they can marshal a wide range of resources—particularly nebulous ones such as “corporate culture” and “collective knowledge”—that markets cannot access. Companies can organise production and create knowledge in unique ways. They can also make long-term bets on innovations that will redefine markets rather than merely satisfy demand. Mr Coase's theory of “market failure” needs to be complemented by a theory of “organisational advantages”.

All this undoubtedly complicates “The Nature of the Firm”. But it also vindicates the twin decisions that Mr Coase made all those years ago as a young student at the London School of Economics: to look inside the black box rather than simply ignoring it, and to examine businesses, not just fiddle with theories. Is it too much to hope that other practitioners of the dismal science will follow his example and study the real world?

This article appeared in the Business section of the print edition

Williamson, Oliver E. 1981. "The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach." American Journal of Sociology 87:548-577.


The transaction cost approach regards the transaction as the basic unit of analysis and holds that understanding of transaction cost economizing is central to the study of organizations through assessing how their governance structures serve to economize on these transaction costs.

I. Antecedents

II. Some rudiments

"A transaction occurs when a good or service is transferred across a technogically separable interface". Is the transaction easy and harmonious, or are their frequent misunderstandings and delays? Transaction cost analysis is about the comparative costs of planning, adapting, and monitoring task completion under alternative governance structures" p. 552

This theory presupposes that human agents are subject to bounded rationality and that some agents are given to opportunism. But for bounded rationality, all economic exchange could be efficiently organized by contract. And people can also be dishonest in economic transactions. "A different way of saying it is that while organizational man is computationally less competent than economic man, he is motivationally more complex".

In a perfect market opportunism can be avoided and punished over time, but not when there are small numbers of exchangers.

The critical dimensions for transactions are 1) uncertainty 2) frequency, 3)degree of durability

Asset specificity is important because it means that future trades are tied to this transaction, when specifics about the trader become important in deciding who to trade with. Asset specificity can be related to site, physical asset, and human asset (i.e. learned knowledge as a result of the transaction).

"The reason asset specificity is critical is that, once an investment has been made, buyer and seller are effectively operating in a bilater (or at least quasi-bilateral) exchange relation for a considerable period thereafter.

 

III. Efficient Boundaries

Decided what transactions are to be included in the organization effectively defines the organizaitonal boundary.

If assets are nonspecific, markets enjoy advantages in both production cost and governance cost respects; static scale economies can be more fully exhausted by buying instead of making; markets can also aggregate uncorrelated demands, thereby realizing risk-pooling benefits; and external procurement avoids many of the hazards to which internal procruement is subject". p. 558

The advantages of firms over markets are:

* internal organization are able to invoke fiat to resolve differences

* better access to information

Incentive to shift transactions inside the firm increases with uncertainty. Some examples are the Fischer body company and GM, forward integration into distribution

 

IV. Managing Human Assets: The Employment Relation

According to transaction-cost approach, "skills acquired in a learning-by-doing fashion and imperfectly transferable across employees need to be embedded in a protective governence structure......

Human assets can also be measured by 1) degree of firm-specificy and 2) difficulty of individual productivity measurability Low of 1 and 2 is a internal spot labor market. Low 1/High 2 is a primative team. High 1/Low 2 is an obligational market with defined rules for performance. High1/High 2 is the relational team where assets are specific and individual output hard to measure.

Comparisons with Organizational Literature

There are so many organizational types because each is optimized for different types of transactions. Unlike the abstract population ecology model, it offers predictions as to which particular organizations will have superior properties in which circumstances.

Williamson and Thompson agree on both coordination costs and the importance of the technical core, but he doesn't define measurable quantities for his variables.

Power

Power is rather tautological and can be applied to anything.

Conclusions

Governance structures that have better transactional cost economizing properties will eventually displace those that have worse.

0 Thoughts to “Strengths Of Transaction Cost Theory Of The Firm Essay

Leave a comment

L'indirizzo email non verrà pubblicato. I campi obbligatori sono contrassegnati *